In E.U. and U.S., Monetary Policy Is Limited

Assertive monetary policy is buying time on both sides of the Atlantic, but we need greater focus on structural factors inhibiting faster growth.

rieder-rick-big.jpg

The initial shock of the global financial crisis on economies worldwide forced central banks into taking dramatic action in 2008, and of course, high degrees of monetary accommodation have been part of our economic and investment landscape ever since. To combat deflationary pressures and anemically growing economies, the world’s largest central banks have been growing their balance sheets to both try to stave off euro zone contagion and to supplement slow velocity of money resulting from depressed levels of credit creation (see Figure 1). The extent of this balance-sheet expansion has been extraordinary, and today major central bank balance sheets are almost as large as 30 percent of global equity market capitalization, up from close to 12 percent in 2008. Central banks will continue their attempt to execute on monetary policy to stimulate growth, avoid deflation risk and maintain low real rates, as we saw last week from the European Central Bank (ECB), but the timing of action is more of an open question, as is its ultimate impact on real economies.

Figure 1: Central Bank Balance Sheet Expansion Continues Apace ($ Trillions)

Central Bank

Central Bank


Source: Deutsche Bank

We expected the ECB would fight to preserve the euro, and consequently it was not surprising to see the aggressive moves announced last week by ECB president Mario Draghi, which are intended to promote peripheral countries’ refinancing ability. Clearly, the loss of market access to capital at a reasonable rate has been the central factor forcing euro zone members into bailout programs, and avoiding or mitigating this eventuality with a large economy is paramount to stability in the region. Velocity of money has been trending down across Europe, as it has been in the U.S., so it makes sense for the ECB to aggressively use its balance sheet until velocity of money picks up and/or until inflation moves higher. To recap the details of the plan: Beyond maintaining its benchmark interest rate at 0.75 percent (and keeping deposit and marginal lending rates stable), the ECB’s Governing Council announced the formation of a new sovereign debt purchase program (Outright Monetary Transactions, or OTM) and it further relaxed its collateral rules. Specifically, the bond-buying program will focus on the 1-year to 3-year segment of the yield curve and the purchasing will be sterilized, which is an attempt at avoiding any overly inflationary outcomes down the road. The OTM does not have a predetermined size, and in an effort to assuage concerns from private market participants, its holdings will not be senior to private creditors but rather will be pari passu. Finally, some amount of conditionality would be imposed on participant countries to help achieve a greater degree of fiscal budgetary discipline. With regard to ECB collateral rule changes, we have already quipped in the past that the ECB was rapidly approaching the point when it might announce that “a used bus ticket isn’t eligible for repo,” in an effort to maintain some standards, but in all seriousness, the rules governing the collateral the central bank will accept have become remarkably lax. For instance, the ECB has effectively suspended the minimum credit rating requirement for many types of collateral. Moreover, the central bank will also now accept non-euro denominated debt securities as collateral, all in the attempt to ensure that collateral shortages are mitigated in the euro zone banking system.

In the end, perhaps we may begin to see a reversal (or at least a slowdown) in the flows of money that have dramatically shifted capital to the euro zone core from the peripheral countries. This eventuality, should it occur, might go some distance toward restoring confidence in the region’s stability, thereby bringing private capital flows back in a meaningful way. The key for policy makers in ensuring that market access remains (at viable interest rate levels) for the majority of the regions’ nonprogram countries (since Greece, Portugal and Ireland are already limited in market access) is first stabilizing and then restoring a high degree of market confidence. The maintenance of confidence, in all forms of investing, is perhaps the dominant, if sometimes underappreciated, component of a credit-based capitalist system. Indeed, the origins of the word “credit” are to be found in the Latin credere, meaning “to believe or to trust,” and these characteristics undergird the activities of lending and borrowing now as much as ever.

Turning briefly to the United States, we still believe that quantitative easing by the Federal Reserve is highly likely to be implemented, despite our view that the U.S. economy is stabilizing and is not likely to fall into recession. There are several reasons for this belief, but a central pillar to the thesis is the fact that the Fed isn’t anywhere close to achieving its mandate of healthy labor markets. The unemployment rate remains elevated, and the employment-to-population ratio has flatlined at an extraordinarily low level. Additionally, we have so far not seen any definitive relationship between U.S. money printing and domestic inflation, although we did make the case last year that QE had influenced inflationary outcomes abroad, which can then result in some imported inflation. Further, as bank lending and credit creation is slowly improving in the U.S., there is a considerable incentive for the Fed to maintain monetary accommodation to facilitate this recovery, as well as to incentivize the corporate sector to increase capital expenditures as economic uncertainty abates.

We shall see if Chairman Bernanke follows Mr. Draghi’s lead this week, and if the Fed does move, we will be watching to see how bold the steps taken are. We believe that the Fed still has considerable room to use more aggressive communications as part of its approach to monetary policy, and we would not be surprised to see the FOMC explicitly introduce the idea of a more open-ended form of quantitative easing, in terms of both purchasing amount and timing. Moreover, they may consider setting either growth or employment triggers that would add predictability to how QE may be implemented. Assertive monetary policy is buying time on both sides of the Atlantic, but at this point we need to see greater focus on the structural factors inhibiting faster growth.

Rick Rieder is BlackRock’s chief investment officer of Fixed Income, Fundamental Portfolios.

See BlackRock’s legal disclaimer here.

Related